全球专业中文经管百科,由121,994位网友共同编写而成,共计436,047个条目

美國貨幣政策

用手机看条目

出自 MBA智库百科(https://wiki.mbalib.com/)

(重定向自美国的货币政策)

美國貨幣政策(United States Monetary Policy)

目錄

美國貨幣政策概述

  美國的貨幣政策的制定和執行職責,長期以來由美國的中央銀行美國聯邦儲備委員會(簡稱美聯儲,FRS)承擔。貨幣政策是美國調控國民經濟和社會發展的主要巨集觀政策工具。美國法律規定,貨幣政策目標是實現充分就業並保持市值的穩定,創造一個相對穩定的金融環境。在貨幣政策執行過程中,美聯儲積極運用有關金融工具以儘量減少利率貨幣信貸量的變化,努力達到兼顧 “充分就業、市值穩定”的兩大目標的目的。隨著市場經濟的成熟和發展,美聯儲貨幣政策在巨集觀調控經濟方面發揮了日益重要的作用。

美國貨幣政策的調控思想及工具的運用

  調控的思想是逆經濟風險行事,衰退時降低準備率和再貼現率,公開市場買入;繁榮時則反過來操作。

  準備金制度原本為了保障商業銀行的流動性,後來演變成控制商業銀行信用創造的工具。

美國貨幣政策調控的效果

  貨幣政策的運用存在著認識時滯、決策時滯和生效時滯,然後使得正確的政策在錯誤的時間發生作用,不是“熨平”,而是擴大經濟的波幅。30年代的大危機據說就是貨幣政策的失誤造成,90年代初格利斯潘的調控實踐也不很成功。

美國貨幣政策調控思想與工具的變化

  90年代以來調控思想主要是,穩定經濟與“逆經濟風向行事”交替,更側重於穩定經濟,也就是儘可能抵消影響經濟波動的因素。

美國貨幣政策的實質

  美國貨幣政策的實質是服務於本國經濟,美聯儲深刻理解美國資產泡沫是美國多年擴張的貨幣造成的,主觀上希望泡沫永遠不會破裂,另一方面通過微調美國經濟、消化歷史包袱。

二戰後美國貨幣政策傳導機制的發展

  1、40-50年代初。1941年,美聯儲為籌措軍費,採取了廉價的貨幣政策,即釘住戰前的低利率:三個月期的國庫券利率為0.375%,長期財政債券利率2.4%。無論什麼時候,只要利率上升到高於上述水平,而且債券價格開始下跌時,美聯儲就進行公開市場購買,迫使利率下降。這一政策在大部分時間內是成功的,但當1950年北韓戰爭爆發時,引起了通貨膨脹。1951年3月,美聯儲和財政部達成“一致協議”,取消釘住利率,但美聯儲承諾它將不讓利率急劇上升。同時,美聯儲正式獨立於財政部,此後貨幣政策才開始具有完全的獨立性,這也標誌著美國貨幣政策開始成為影響美國經濟的主導力量。

  2、50-70年代。這期間美國經濟周期性擴張和收縮的特征非常突出,因此,擴張性貨幣政策緊縮性的貨幣政策交替也很明顯,貨幣政策目標經常變化。50年代,美聯儲控制的中介指標有自由儲備金凈額、三個月期的國庫券利率貨幣總量比,並按此次序來決定指標控制的重要性。結果表明,美聯儲對前兩個指標的控制較好,對貨幣總量控制較差,這導致最初的10年內競發生了三次經濟危機。到了60年代,又重新推行廉價的貨幣政策,同時重視財政政策的運用。貨幣供應量增長率日趨上升,松的貨幣政策加之松的財政政策導致通貨膨脹率不斷上升,從1965年的2.3%到1969年的6.1%。這些政策進一步導致了70年代滯脹的發生。70年代,美聯儲將貨幣總量作為中間目標,從M1 和M2的增長率來看,美聯儲以緊縮的貨幣政策為主,最終導致了1979年的經濟危機。

  3、80-90年代。70年代後,隨著通貨膨脹被抑制,美聯儲又轉向了平穩利率政策,並獲得了極大成功。例如90年代初,美國經濟陷入蕭條,美聯儲在1990年7月到1992年9月間連續逐步降息17次,將短期利率從8%降到3%,促進投資與消費上升,從而帶動了整個經濟的發展。在1994年到1995年7月,美國經濟過熱時,又連續7次提高聯邦基金利率,成功地實現了軟著陸。1994年美聯儲主席格林斯潘指出,美聯儲將放棄以貨幣供應量的增減對經濟實行巨集觀調控的做法,今後將以調控實際利率作為經濟調控的主要手段。這標志著美國貨幣政策的重大轉變。

  4、目前。自1999年6月開始,為防止經濟過熱,美聯儲開始抽緊銀根,半年中先後三次提高利率。但美國經濟增長勢頭仍沒有減緩的跡象,於是在2000年2月2日、3月21日和5月16日又分別提高利率,使聯邦基金利率達到65%。5月底公佈的數據表明力度加大的巨集觀調控開始見效,經濟增長逐步放緩。但2001年伊始,種種跡象表明,美國經濟已進入了明顯放慢的敏感時期。為刺激經濟回升,從1月至6月底,美聯儲連續六次降息。在這麼短的時間內採取如此大的降息動作,是近20年來的第一次。目前,美國聯邦基金利率和貼現率分別為3.75%和3.25%,均為7年多來的最低水平。美聯儲表示,美國經濟今後一段時期面臨的主要危險仍是疲軟,這意味著美聯儲可能還會降息。雖然目前美國經濟還沒有明顯好轉的跡象,但大多數經濟學家認為,下半年美國經濟形勢將會出現好轉。因為,首先,利率調整通常需要6至9個月的時間才能對經濟產生全面影響。這意味著美聯儲今年1月開始的降息行動將在下半年充分發揮作用。其次,布希政府已開始實施其大規模減稅計劃。根據這一計劃,美國家庭下半年可獲得450億美元的減稅。再次,美國的消費者信心已開始回升,個人消費開支可望繼續增加。

美國的貨幣政策與經濟發展

  從美聯儲提供的1971呈2001年美國GDP增長、生產力水平和物價走勢圖可以看出:90年代中後期是美國經濟最活躍的時期,在此期間,美國經濟持續保持高速增長,通貨膨脹率也控制在較低幅度,生產力水平的增長超過了30年的平均水平。在美國過去十年經濟高速增長時期,一個很顯著的特征是各類投資基金發展迅速。風險投資基金的發展,有力支持了新興企業特別是高科技企業不斷成長壯大;併購基金的發展,加快了企業的兼併重組,使一大批企業加快轉型步伐,更多的由傳統行業轉向半導體、電信、信息技術等新興產業,居民及企業投資意願旺盛。

  隨著經濟快速增長,1998年以來,美國經濟也不同程度上出現投資過度、投機增加等泡沫經濟現象,一些新興企業股價被嚴重高估,如從事信息網路業務的亞馬遜公司股票市值在一段時間竟與通用公司的市值幾乎相當,嚴重背離了實際情況。為了防止經濟進一步過熱,美聯儲在兩年曾連續7次提高貸款利息,促使市場修正過熱的經濟預期,導致美國股市回落,企業投資特別是高新技術領域投資明顯下降,經濟增長逐步趨緩。

  2000年第四季度開始,美國經濟增長出現停滯之勢。2000年以來,為了防止經濟衰退,提升企業和個人投資意願,促進經濟增長,尤其是振興 “9.11”事件後遭受重大打擊的美國經濟,美聯儲又連續11次降息,美元一年期浮動利率從原來的6.5%下降到1.75%,以刺激居民消費和投資的增長。美聯儲有關官員認為:從近30年來美國生產力水平曲線圖可以看出,這次美國經濟衰退與歷史上其他時期的經濟衰退有所不同。由於美國生產力水平仍保持在基本高於平均增長值狀況,競爭力仍屬較高水平,因此美國經濟有望在今年下半年開始複蘇,並逐步進入新一輪增長。

美國貨幣政策的目標

  Judd, Rudebusch

  下麵是一封舊金山聯邦儲備銀行的經濟學通信。裡面談到了美國的貨幣政策目標及其歷史演變。1913年,美聯儲成立的時候,沒有規定目標,只說它的作用是維持貨幣彈性。1946年《就業法》規定美聯儲的貨幣政策目標是促進最大就業。1977年和1978年的《全面就業和預算平衡法》規定,貨幣政策有三個:“完全就業,價格穩定,中長期利率平穩”。現在,正在爭論是否將貨幣政策目標只減為保持價格穩定這一項。歐洲央行已經這樣做了。

================

FRBSF Economic Letter

99-04; January 29, 1999

The Goals of U.S. Monetary Policy

* The evolution of the Fed's legislative mandate * The debate about the Fed's current mandate * References

The Federal Reserve has seen its legislative mandate for monetary policy change several times since its founding in 1913, when macroeconomic policy as such was not clearly understood. The most recent revisions were in 1977 and 1978, and they require the Fed to promote both price stability and full employment. The past changes in the mandate appear to reflect both economic events in the U.S. and advances in understanding how the economy functions. In the twenty years since the Fed's mandate was last changed, there have been further important economic developments as well as refinements in economic thought, and these raise the issue of whether to modify the goals for U.S. monetary policy once again. Indeed, a number of other countries--notably those that adopted the Euro as a common curency at the start of this year--have accepted price stability as the new primary goal for their monetary policies.

In this Letter, we spell out the evolution of the legislation governing U.S. monetary policy goals and summarize the debate about whether they could be improved.

The evolution of the Fed's legislative mandate

  1913年的《美聯儲法案》沒有將任何巨集觀經濟目標納入貨幣政策,而是要求美聯儲“提供彈性貨幣”這意味著美聯儲應該通過充當“最後貸款人”來幫助經濟避免困擾19世紀的金融恐慌和銀行擠兌,後者包括通過儲備銀行的貼現視窗直接向存款機構發放貸款。在這個早期階段,影響巨集觀經濟的大多數貨幣政策行動都是由美國政府對金本位的堅持所決定的。

The trauma of the Great Depression, coupled with the insights of Keynes (1936), led to an acknowledgment of the obligation of the federal government to prevent recessions. The Employment Act of 1946 was the first legislative statement of these macroeconomic policy goals. Although it did not specifically mention the Federal Reserve, it required the federal government in general to foster "conditions under which there will be afforded useful employment opportunities ... for those able, willing, and seeking to work, and to promote maximum employment, production, and purchasing power."

The Great Inflation of the 1970s was the next major U.S. economic dislocation. This problem was addressed in a 1977 amendment to the Federal Reserve Act, which provided the first explicit recognition of price stability as a national policy goal. The amended Act states that the Fed "shall maintain long run growth of the monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with the economy's long run potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates." The goals of "stable prices" and "moderate long-term interest rates" are related because nominal interest rates are boosted by a premium over real rates equal to expected future inflation. Thus, "stable prices" will typically produce long-term interest rates that are "moderate."

The objective of "maximum" employment remained intact from the 1946 Employment Act; however, the interpretation of this term may have changed during the intervening 30 years. Immediately after World War II, when conscription and price controls had produced a high-pressure economy with very low unemployment in the U.S., some perhaps believed that the goal of "maximum" employment could be taken in its mathematical sense to mean the highest possible level of employment. However, by the second half of the 1970s, it was well understood that some "frictional" unemployment, which involves the search for new jobs and the transition between occupations, is a necessary accompaniment to the proper functioning of the economy in the long run.

This understanding went hand in hand in the latter half of the 1970s with a general acceptance of the Natural Rate Hypothesis, which implies that if policy were to try to keep employment above its long-run trend permanently or, equivalently, the unemployment rate below its natural rate, then inflation would be pushed higher and higher. Policy can temporarily reduce the unemployment rate below its natural rate or, equivalently, boost employment above its long-run trend. However, persistently attempting to maintain "maximum" employment that is above its long-run level would not be consistent with the goal of stable prices.

Thus, in order for maximum employment and stable prices to be mutually consistent goals, maximum employment should be interpreted as meaning maximum sustainable employment, referred to also as "full employment." Moreover, although the Fed has little if any influence on the long-run level of employment, it can attempt to smooth out short-run fluctuations. Accordingly, promoting full employment can be interpreted as a countercyclical monetary policy in which the Fed aims to smooth out the amplitude of the business cycle.

This interpretation of the Fed's mandate was later confirmed in the Humphrey-Hawkins legislation. As its official title--the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978--clearly implies, this legislation mandates the federal government generally to "...promote full employment and production, increased real income, balanced growth, a balanced Federal budget, adequate productivity growth, proper attention to national priorities, achievement of an improved trade balance . . . and reasonable price stability..." (italics added).

Besides clarifying the general goal of full employment, the Humphrey-Hawkins Act also specified numerical definitions or targets. The Act specified two initial goals: an unemployment rate of 4% for full employment and a CPI inflation rate of 3% for price stability. These were only "interim" goals to be achieved by 1983 and followed by a further reduction in inflation to 0% by 1988; however, the disinflation policies during this period were not to impede the achievement of the full-employment goal. Thereafter, the timetable to achieve or maintain price stability and full employment was to be defined by each year's Economic Report of the President.

The debate about the Fed's current mandate

The Fed then has two main legislated goals for monetary policy: promoting full employment and promoting stable prices. With this mandate, the Fed has helped foster the exceptional performance of the U.S. economy during the past decade. Still, some have argued that the Fed's mandate could be improved, especially in looking ahead to future attempts to maintain or institutionalize recent low inflation. Much discussion has centered on two topics: the transparency of the goals and their dual nature.

The transparency of goals refers to the extent to which the objectives of monetary policy are clearly defined and can be easily and obviously understood by the public. The goal of full employment will never be very transparent because it is not directly observed but only estimated by economists with limited precision. For example, the 1997 Economic Report of the President (which has authority in this matter from the Humphrey-Hawkins Act) gives a range of 5 to 6% for the unemployment rate consistent with full employment, with a midpoint of 5.5%. Research suggests that there is a very wide range of uncertainty around any estimate of the natural rate, with one prominent study finding a 95% probability that it falls in the wide range of 4 to 7-1/2 % (see Walsh 1998).

Price stability as a goal is also subject to some ambiguity. Recent economic analysis has uncovered systematic biases, say, on the order of 1 percentage point, in the CPI's measurement of inflation (see Motley 1997). In this case, actual price stability would be consistent with measured inflation of 1%. In addition, at any point in time, different price indexes register different rates of inflation. Over the past year, for example, the CPI has risen about 1-1/2%, while the GDP price index has risen about 1%. Still, a transparent price stability goal could be specified as a precise numerical growth rate (or range) for a particular index (which could take into account any biases). However, economists have also suggested other ways to enhance the transparency of policy. For example, publishing medium-term inflation forecasts might help to clarify the direction of policy (Rudebusch and Walsh 1998). Because the central bank has some control over inflation in the medium term, its forecasts would contain an indication of where it wanted inflation to go.

A second recent proposed modification to the Fed's goals involves focusing to a larger extent on price stability and de-emphasizing business cycle stabilization. Some economists have argued that having dual goals will lead to an inflation bias despite the Fed's best attempts to control inflation. This argument stresses that the temptation to engineer gains in output in the short run will overcome the central bank's desire to control inflation in the long run. As a result of elevated inflation expectations of the public, inflation will end up being higher than the central bank intended, despite its best efforts. This "time-inconsistency" argument, as economists call it, coupled with the pain incurred in the 1970s as inflation skyrocketed and in the early 1980s as inflation was reduced to moderate levels, persuaded many that the primary goal of the central bank should be to stabilize prices.

This view is embodied in the charter for the central bank in the new European Monetary Union: "The primary objective of the European System of Central Banks is to maintain price stability. Without prejudice to the objective of price stability, the ESCB shall support the general economic policies in the Community." Among these latter policies are "a high level of employment" and "a balanced development of economic activities."

Economists remain divided on the importance of the time inconsistency problem and on the need to put primary emphasis on price stability at the expense of output stabilization. Some stress the fact that the central bank is the only entity that can guarantee price stability, and that this goal is not likely to be attained for long unless price stability is designated as the primary goal. Others find the arguments for time inconsistency implausible because policymakers, who are aware of the arguments about an inflationary bias and see the implications for inflation, can conduct policy without an inflationary bias (McCallum 1995). Still others argue that the abdication of other goals is irresponsible (Fuhrer 1997). Also, a good deal of empirical research using simulations of models of the U.S. economy suggests that a focus on dual goals can reduce the variance of real GDP (i.e., smooth the business cycle) while achieving an inflation goal as well (Rudebusch and Svensson 1998).

While these issues are not yet resolved, the experience of the past two decades provides some support to those who think dual goals that lack transparency can function successfully. It is true that some countries around the world have reduced inflation over this period while putting primary emphasis on explicit inflation targeting. But at the same time, with its current legislative mandate, the Fed also has had success in reducing inflation, while maintaining the flexibility of responding to business cycle conditions.

John P. Judd Vice President and Associate Director of Research

Glenn D. Rudebusch Research Officer References

Fuhrer, Jeffrey C. 1997. "Central Bank Independence and Inflation Targeting: Monetary Policy Paradigms for the Next Millennium?" New England Economic Review January/February, pp.20-36. Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Harcourt, Brace, and Company: New York.

McCallum, Bennett. 1995. "Two Fallacies Concerning Central Bank Independence." American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, vol. 85, no. 2 (May), pp. 207-211.

Motley, Brian. 1997. "Bias in the CPI: Roughly Wrong or Precisely Wrong." FRBSF Economic Letter 97-16 (May 23).

Rudebusch, Glenn D., and Lars E.O. Svensson. 1998. "Policy Rules for Inflation Targeting." NBER Working Paper 6512.

Rudebusch Glenn D., and Carl E. Walsh. 1998. "U.S. Inflation Targeting: Pro and Con." FRBSF Economic Letter 98-18 (May 29).

Walsh, Carl E. 1998. "The Natural Rate, NAIRU, and Monetary Policy." FRBSF Economic Letter 98-28 (September 18).

美國貨幣政策大事記

1942年美國參加第二次世界大戰。FED應財政部的要求正式承擔保持國債低利率的義務。財政部需要低成本的資金來為戰爭籌款。FED因此不得不放棄貨幣存量的目標,專註於控制利率。
1950年北韓戰爭爆發。財政部希望FED繼續承擔保持低利率的責任,而FED更希望控制戰爭帶來的通貨膨脹壓力,雙方發生矛盾。
1951年3月4日FED和財政部簽署《財政部和聯邦儲備系統協議》(the Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord),該協議終結了FED支持美國國債價格的義務,確保了聯儲制定和執行貨幣政策的獨立性。在該協議之前,美國沒有獨立的貨幣政策,貨幣政策只是財政政策的附庸。
1958年11月.W.Phillips發表《The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdoms,1861-1957》(Economica, November 1958, pp. 283-299)。它的直接含義就是通貨膨脹與失業率之間存在替代關係,這篇文章的發表標志著Phillips Curve曲線的發現。
1975年美國開始試驗貨幣增長量目標制(Money-Growth Targeting)。FED宣佈對三個主要的貨幣總量:M1、M2、M3的目標增長範圍。由於實際上FED在存款方面能夠控制的,只是基礎貨幣,所以要想同時達到這三個不同的貨幣總量目標,實際上是不現實的。事實上,FED經常達不到它事先宣佈的目標,經常有很大的誤差。貨幣主義者聲稱,FED同時宣佈三個不同的貨幣總量目標,表明它對於實行固定的貨幣增長規則並非十分嚴肅。
1979年8月保羅·沃爾克就任FED主席。兩個月後,他說服聯邦公開市場委員會FOMC)的同僚們贊同削減通貨膨脹,使他們相信聯儲的運作程式需要根本性的變化。1978年的通貨膨脹率為9%,1979年為12%。通貨膨脹率的激增,使得FED下定決心對付通貨膨脹問題。
1979年10月FED宣佈,它致力於貨幣供應的緩慢增長,將樂於預設更大更頻繁的短期利率變動。這標志著FED操作程式的重大改變,FED將貨幣政策的中介目標集中到M2上,而放棄了短期利率。在這之後,利率迅速上升,而經濟低迷。卡特政府對這一做法並沒有表示反對。
1980年3月短期利率超過15%,聯儲失去了卡特政府的支持。因為距離總統大選不到9個月了,卡特總統授權聯儲對信貸實行強行管制,並連續利用電視媒體有力地勸誡消費者抑制信貸的使用。在接下來的三個月里,經濟明顯地衰退了。FED將短期利率幾乎削減了一半,以應對貨幣存量的下降。這個措施更像是為了在大選年扭轉衰退的嘗試,而不是聯儲瞄準貨幣總量的新政策的利率後果。利率降低以後,經濟有所複蘇。非常短期的緊縮貨幣政策和微弱的經濟複蘇,不足以降低通貨膨脹率。
80年代初期在實踐貨幣增長目標制的期間,美國、德國、英國、加拿大的通貨膨脹率確實都顯著下降,但是它們的產出和失業率也變得很不穩定,失業率都顯著上升。
1982年由於無法接受失業率上升,FED宣佈不再特別強調實行貨幣增長目標制(Money-growth targeting),轉而更重視利率目標制(Interest Rate Targeting)。
1993年FED宣佈徹底廢止使用貨幣增長目標制。在此之前的80年代,其他實行貨幣增長目標制的國家也已經紛紛不再實行(德國和瑞士除外,不過德國也在 1987年宣佈將貨幣增長的目標從中央銀行貨幣轉為M3)。FED解釋的原因是70年代和80年代,貨幣需求頻繁變動,十分不穩定。這時,如果依然保持貨幣供給不變,就會造成利率的劇烈變動,這對經濟是很不利的。
本條目對我有幫助53
MBA智库APP

扫一扫,下载MBA智库APP

分享到:
  如果您認為本條目還有待完善,需要補充新內容或修改錯誤內容,請編輯條目投訴舉報

評論(共6條)

提示:評論內容為網友針對條目"美國貨幣政策"展開的討論,與本站觀點立場無關。
202.98.100.* 在 2008年5月12日 15:59 發表

不懂。

回複評論
222.76.36.* 在 2008年12月17日 20:12 發表

不錯

回複評論
219.234.81.* 在 2009年12月23日 19:33 發表

很好~~

回複評論
58.212.233.* 在 2012年3月12日 10:03 發表

成熟的自由經濟 人類最好的貨幣體制

回複評論
223.129.0.* 在 2013年6月15日 20:17 發表

58.212.233.* 在 2012年3月12日 10:03 發表

成熟的自由經濟 人類最好的貨幣體制

不見得吧

回複評論
123.124.19.* 在 2013年12月31日 14:24 發表

58.212.233.* 在 2012年3月12日 10:03 發表

成熟的自由經濟 人類最好的貨幣體制

顯然是片面的而且過於絕對的觀點

回複評論

發表評論請文明上網,理性發言並遵守有關規定。

打开APP

以上内容根据网友推荐自动排序生成

官方社群
下载APP

闽公网安备 35020302032707号